Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Gautam Kalghatgi's avatar

Hi, apart from electricity generation, there is the other commitment to reduce greenhouse gas emissions (GHG) by 81% by 2035 compared to 1990, made by Keir Starmer at COP29.

From Statistical Review of World Energy 2024, in 1990, U.K. CO2 equivalent emissions from energy, process emissions, methane and flaring were 595 million tonnes. So by 2035 they need to be 113 million tonnes. In 2023 they were 327 million tonnes. So if other GHG sources ( e.g. from farming) are ignored, fossil fuel energy consumption has to be reduced by 65% by 2035 compared to 2023. Now, in 2023, fossil fuels, mostly oil and gas, provided 5.16 exajoules (EJ) of primary energy. If U.K. has to replace 65% of this, it has to find 3.35 EJ of new CO2-free energy. Even if we assume that miraculously U.K. will reduce its primary energy requirement by 40%, it still has to find 2.01 EJ of new CO2-free energy. This is equivalent to providing 65 GW of continuous CO2-free energy or around 22 new Hinckley Point C nuclear power plants or 145 GW of new wind assuming a very optimistic capacity factor, CF of 0.45. For refernce, CF for wind currently is 0.31(for solar it is 0.11) and installed wind capacity is around 31 GW. So almost everything has to be run on CO2-free electricity There also has to be a massive change in lifestyle on top of the 40% reduction in primary energy consumption assumed - enormous reductions, almost to zero, in meat and dairy consumption, aviation , cement and steel industries . …

All this will be impossible to achieve in the real world by 2035. Anyway, what would be the cost of all this if it were possible?

Expand full comment
It doesn't add up...'s avatar

This is a tremendous piece of work. I know just how much effort is required to pull something like this together having done various analyses myself. So well done.

It underscores the idea that the markets have changed how they operate and backs it with hard analysis, as well as showing that the Miliband plan is in reality a high cost option. I think it's possible to discern many of your findings when closely looking at a chart of electricity supply by source with a price overlay like this one:

https://i0.wp.com/wattsupwiththat.com/wp-content/uploads/2024/08/Generation-jan-2023-1722888879.3157.png

I have yet to complete my analysis of 2024 because of the need for data cleaning which can be very time consuming. However, it is easy to see that intraday price volatility is huge, particularly when there is a high share of renewables on the system. When it is windy there are huge swings in interconnector supply between net export and large imports, and pumped storage also plays a role. Back then batteries were small beer, and only reported for net discharge AFAICS under the OTHER categroy of generation. Downloading individual metered readings for batteries only shows the net charge or discharge over a settlement period, not the total input for charging/cooling and discharge output, so it is hard to get good information on battery performance, and unfortunately Bess Analytics has now disappeared behind a paywall having been acquired by Cornwall Insight, so now we depend on commentary from the like of ModoEnergy for analysis (they are very good though).

If we rearrange the data in price order we get a chart like this

https://i0.wp.com/wattsupwiththat.com/wp-content/uploads/2024/05/Gen-by-Price-Jan-2023-1716328267.549.png

which shows clearly that when wind output dominates prices are set by competition between wind sources, and tend close to zero or negative when we have a surplus export. Subsidising exports for the benefit of foreign consumers has never made sense to me. As capacity increases we will see more hours with wind surpluses and the surpluses will grow in low demand hours. It is clear that the structure of the market will concentrate curtailment on those wind farms that get no compensation when prices are negative. We can see this already with Seagreen and Moray East, which have yet to take up CFDs and become the dominant volumes of curtailment. The price they have been getting has been steadily reducing too, as more competition starts to come on stream from other wind farms in construction which also get no subsidy protection.

Incidentally, I think you are incorrect about ROCs in your Annex. For now they remain traded, although the market is very opaque and not openly reported unless you subscribe to a specialist price reporter like ICIS. However, the final recycle value of ROCs that includes the premium for redistribution of the cashout fund is published (often obscurely) by OFGEM. REF has a convenient table of the history at the bottom of the page here:

https://www.ref.org.uk/energy-data/notes-on-the-renewable-obligation

I am using an assumption of a 12% premium for the current year, giving a value of £72.50/ROC, as a guess that allows for slightly disappointing actual output from renewables and probably more stable demand. Up for consultation is a proposal to fix the ROC value without trading at a 10% uplift to the indexed cashout value for the life of the scheme between 2027 and 2037 when it expires, because it is anticipated that the balance between the obligation and supply could become much more volatile in future.

Expand full comment
41 more comments...

No posts